Monday 10 May 2010


30 April 2010


Image of the cover page of Intereconomics

VOLUME 45 · ISSUE 2 · MARCH/APRIL 2010

Contents

FORUM

Challenges Facing European Monetary Union

With articles by D. Gros, T. Mayer, U. Häde, J. Pisani-Ferry, A. Sapir, J. Matthes, D. Mabbett, W. Schelkle, W. Kösters, P. Grauwe, D. Lachman

OTHER ARTICLES

  • Carsten Hefeker · A French Plot to Undermine Monetary Stability
  • Bernd Braasch · Financial Market Crisis and Financial Market Channel
  • Markus C. Kerber · The Galileo Project Put to the Test of European Competition and Public Procurement Law
  • Phedon Nicolaides · A Model of Europeanisation with and without Convergence
  • Alessia Lo Turco, Aleksandra Parteka · EU Enlargement and Labour Demand in the New Member States

Forum: Challenges Facing European Monetary Union

While past discussions on EMU tended to emphasise its role in limiting the impact of the global financial crisis on the euro area countries, the focus has now shifted to the destabilising effects threatening the entire euro zone as a consequence of the dire fiscal situation in some weaker member countries, notably Greece. Will the EMU be able to pass the first serious challenge it faces or is it a fair-weather construction with basic design flaws? What options are available to policymakers?

Contents:

How to Deal with the Threat of Sovereign Default in Europe: Towards a Euro(pean) Monetary Fund - Daniel Gros and Thomas Mayer

Legal Evaluation of a European Monetary Fund - Ulrich Häde

Crisis Resolution in the Euro Area: An Alternative to the European Monetary Fund - Jean Pisani-Ferry and André Sapir

The IMF is Better Suited than an EMF to Deal with Potential Sovereign Defaults in the Eurozone - Jürgen Matthes

Beyond the Crisis – The Greek Conundrum and EMU Reform - Deborah Mabbett and Waltraud Schelkle

Challenges Facing European Monetary Union – Rules and Assignment or Discretion and Coordination? - Wim Kösters

The Greek Crisis and the Future of the Eurozone - Paul De Grauwe

Greece’s Threat to the Euro - Desmond Lachman

Intereconomics Vol.45, No.2, March-April 2010, p64-95

(Gros, Daniel)

http://www.intereconomics.eu/

http://www.intereconomics.eu/downloads/getfile.php?id=725


----------------------------------------


Forum 
DOI: 10.1007/s10272-010-0326-7 
Forum 
DOI: 10.1007/s10272-010-0326-7 
Challenges Facing European Monetary Union 


While past discussions on EMU tended to emphasise its role in limiting the impact of the 
global financial crisis on the euro area countries, the focus has now shifted to the destabilising 
effects threatening the entire euro zone as a consequence of the dire fiscal situation in some 
weaker member countries, notably Greece. Will the EMU be able to pass the fi rst serious 
challenge it faces or is it a fair-weather construction with basic design flaws? What options are 
available to policymakers? 

Daniel Gros and Thomas Mayer 

How to Deal with the Threat of Sovereign Default in Europe: 
Towards a Euro(pean) Monetary Fund* 

The case of Greece has ushered in the second phase of 
the financial crisis, namely that of a public debt crisis. 
Members of the euro area were supposed to be shielded 
from a financial market meltdown. But after excess 
spending during the period of easy credit, several euro 
area members are now grappling with the implosion of 
credit-financed construction and consumption booms. 
Greece is the weakest of the weak links, given its high 
public debt (around 120% of GDP), compounded by a 
government budget deficit of almost 13% of GDP, a huge 
external deficit of 11% of GDP and the loss of credibility 
from its repeated cheating on budget reports. 

Greece – as well as others in the EU, notably Portugal and 
Spain – must therefore undergo painful adjustments in 
government finances and external competitiveness if their 
public debt positions are to become sustainable again. 
But given the intense pressure from fi nancial markets, 
it is likely that in some cases a tough fi scal adjustment 
programme (or rather the promise that one will be forthcoming) 
might not be enough to avoid a “sudden stop” of 
external funding of the public sector. When this happens, 
the euro area will no longer be able to fudge the question 
of whether (and in what form) it can provide public fi nancial 
support to one of its members. 

One way out of this dilemma seems to be to call in the 
IMF. In principle, the conditions for taking this route have 
been clarified at the European Council of 25 March 2010. 

This paper is based on D. Gros, T. Mayer: How to deal with sovereign 
default in Europe: Towards a Euro(pean) Monetary Fund, CEPS 
Policy Brief No. 202, Centre for European Policy Studies, Brussels, 
February 2010. 
“As part of a package involving substantial International 
Monetary Fund financing and a majority of European fi nancing, 
Euro area member states, are ready to contribute 
to coordinated bilateral loans. This mechanism, complementing 
International Monetary Fund fi nancing, has 
to be considered ultima ratio, meaning in particular that 
market financing is insufficient. Any disbursement on the 
bilateral loans would be decided by the euro area member 
states by unanimity subject to strong conditionality 
and based on an assessment by the European Commission 
and the European Central Bank.”1 

However, it is also clear that the IMF would not be able to 
solve the Greek problem on its own since the amount of 
financial assistance it could give to the country is limited 
to about € 10-15 billion, a fraction of Greece’s estimated 
financing need for 2010 alone. This is why the statement 
from the Heads of State of the Euro Area foresees that the 
majority of the financing would be European and any disbursement 
would be decided by euro area member states 
(by unanimity). 

This package which has now been agreed to for the case 
of Greece is clearly designed to deal with a potential 
emergency situation in an ad hoc manner. 

We would argue, however, that this is not a satisfactory 
approach in general. The EU needs to design a scheme 
capable of dealing with the threat of sovereign default. 

 If 

Statement by the Heads of State and Government of the Euro Area, 

available at http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/ 

docs/pressdata/en/ec/113563.pdf 

Intereconomics 2010 | 2 

64 

Forum Forum 
the IMF were called in to help and the country concerned 
(today Greece, but tomorrow another country) refused to 
comply with the conditions of a support programme, the 
problem would only be magnified. The debtor country, 
like Greece today, would retain its main negotiating asset, 
namely the threat of a disorderly default, creating systemic 
financial instability in the EU and possibly at the global 
level. This dilemma could be avoided by creating a “European 
Monetary Fund” (EMF), which would be capable of 
organising an orderly default as a measure of last resort. 

Our proposal for an EMF can also be seen as a complement 
to the ideas presently under discussion for allowing 
orderly defaults of private financial institutions and rescue 
funds for large banks that would be funded by the 
industry itself. The analogy holds in more general terms: 
in the recent financial crisis, policy has been geared solely 
towards preventing the failure of large institutions. In the 
future, however, the key policy aim must be to restore 
market discipline by making failure possible. For EMU this 
means that the system should be made robust enough to 
minimise the disruption caused by the failure of one of its 
member states. 

Purists will object to our scheme on the ground that it 
violates the “no-bailout” provision of the Maastricht Treaty.
2 However, we would argue that our proposal is actually 
the only way to make the no-bailout rule credible and 
thus give teeth to the threat not to bail a country out. The 
drafters of the Maastricht Treaty had failed to appreciate 
that, in a context of fragile financial markets, the perceived 
(and real) danger of a financial meltdown makes a 
“pure” no-bailout response unrealistic. As with the case 
of large, systemically important banks, market discipline 
can be made credible only if there are clear provisions 
that minimise the disruptions to markets in case of failure. 

Key Issues for the Design of a European Monetary 
Fund 

Any mutualisation of risks creates a moral hazard because 
it blunts market signals. This would argue against 
any mutual support mechanism and for reliance on fi nancial 
markets to enforce fiscal discipline. However, experience 
has shown repeatedly that market signals can 
remain weak for a long time and are often dominated by 
swings in risk appetite which can be quite violent. Hence, 
in reality the case for reliance on market signals as an enforcement 
mechanism for fiscal discipline is quite weak. 
In fact, swings in risk appetite and other forces that have 
little to do with the creditworthiness of a country can lead 
to large swings in yield differentials and even credit ra


tioning that have little to do with economic fundamentals. 
The moral hazard problem can never be completely 
neutralised, but for our proposal it could be limited in 
two ways: through the financing mechanism of the EMF 
and via the conditionality attached to its support. These 
points will be discussed first, followed by a brief analysis 
of two equally important issues, namely enforcement and 
orderly default. 

Contributors to this Forum 

Daniel Gros, Centre for European Policy Studies 
(CEPS), Brussels, Belgium, and CEPR. 

Thomas Mayer, Deutsche Bank. 

Ulrich Häde, European University Viadrina Frankfurt 
(Oder), Germany. 

Jean Pisani-Ferry, Bruegel, Brussels, Belgium, 
and Université Paris-Dauphine, France. 

André Sapir, Université Libre de Bruxelles and 
Bruegel, Brussels, Belgium. 

Jürgen Matthes, Cologne Institute for Economic 
Research (Institut der deutschen Wirtschaft Köln), 
Germany. 

Deborah Mabbett, Birkbeck, University of London, 
UK, and Hanse Wissenschaftskolleg, Delmenhorst, 
Germany. 

Waltraud Schelkle, London School of Economics 
and Political Science, London, UK, and Hanse Wissenschaftskolleg, 
Delmenhorst, Germany. 

Wim Kösters, Ruhr Universität Bochum and Rheinisch-
Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung, 
Essen, Germany. 

Paul de Grauwe, University of Leuven, Belgium. 

Desmond Lachman, American Enterprise Institute 
(AEI), Washington, DC, USA. 

2 Article 125 of the TFEU (formerly Article 103 TEC). 

Intereconomics 2010 | 2 

Forum Forum 
Financing Mechanism 

A simple mechanism to limit the moral hazard problem 
would be to ensure that the main contributions would 
come from those countries that breach the Maastricht criteria. 
The contribution rates would be calculated on the 
following basis: 

...........................................


Final Conclusion extract



Greece’s Threat to the Euro 

All too often in the midst of an economic and fi nancial 
crisis, policymakers either engage in denial or else take 
flights into fantasy. Sadly, the present Greek crisis is 
proving to be no exception. Rather than recognising the 
Greek crisis for the solvency issue that it is, European 
policymakers seem to be convincing themselves that foreign 
speculation is at the core of the crisis. And at a time 
when the European economic house is burning, European 
policymakers are now indulging in the fantasy that 
an inevitably tortuous Treaty modification allowing for the 
establishment of a European Monetary Fund will have 
any relevance for the resolution of the present Greek crisis. 


A more realistic analysis of Greece’s present economic 
situation would reveal that Greece now poses a very real 
existential threat to the continuation of the euro in its 
present form. This is not simply because of the extraordinarily 
large internal and external imbalances that Greece 
is now trying to address within the straightjacket of eurozone 
membership. Rather, it is because similar imbalances 
are shared to a disturbingly high degree by the very 
much larger Spanish economy as well as by the economies 
of Portugal and Ireland. 

European policymakers’ understandable reluctance to 
own up to the solvency problems facing by the countries 
at the eurozone’s periphery will not make these 
problems go away. Nor will repeated bailouts of these 
countries do more than kick the can forward. What it will 
do, however, is distract attention from the most basic of 
questions that Europe will have to confront within the 
next year or two. How is the euro to be restructured in 
a manner that inflicts the least damage possible on the 
European economy? 

Greece’s Solvency Problem 

At a time when European policymakers are contemplating 
banning naked CDS positions and embarking on the 

drawn-out process of setting up a European Monetary 
Fund, the Greek economic crisis is playing out in real time. 
At the root of the crisis is Greece’s longstanding failure to 
remotely live up to its Maastricht Treaty obligations with 
respect to its public finances. Indeed, from the moment 
that Greece adopted the euro in 2001, the Greek authorities 
have been engaged in shameless creative budget accounting 
that evidently misled not only Greece’s eurozone 
partners but Greek policymakers themselves. 

Last October, after a new Greek government took office, 
markets were rudely reminded of how fast and 
loose Greece has been with its public spending and 
budget reporting. It was then that Mr. Papandreou, the 
newly elected Greek prime minister, shocked markets 
by owning up to the fact that Greece’s budget deficit 
in 2009 would be around 12 ¾ percentage points of 
GDP or around double the former officially projected 
number. It is little wonder that of all the eurozone member 
countries, Greece has received the worst ratings 
from the credit rating agencies. It is even less wonder 
that the Greek government now has to pay the highest 
interest rates in the eurozone on its sovereign borrowing. 


Greece’s budget largesse has clearly put the country’s 
public finances on an unsustainable path. This is suggested 
by a budget deficit that is more than four times 
the Maastricht criteria’s limit of 3 per cent of GDP. It is 
also underlined by a public debt to GDP ratio that is 
expected to exceed 120 per cent by the end of 2010. 
Equally disturbing is the fact that budget profl igacy, 
coupled with inappropriately low ECB interest rates for 
Greece, has resulted in persistently higher wage and 
price inflation in Greece than in the rest of the eurozone. 
Since adopting the euro in 2001, Greece is estimated 
to have lost around 30 percentage points in unit labour 
competitiveness, which has contributed to a widening 
in its external current account deficit well into the double 
digits in relation to GDP. 

Intereconomics 2010 | 2 

Forum Forum 
The sad reality is that Greece’s domestic and external 
imbalances have reached such a dimension that their 
correction within the straightjacket of eurozone membership 
will necessarily involve many years of painful 
deflation and deep economic recession. Lacking 
its own currency, Greece cannot restore international 
competitiveness through currency depreciation. Nor 
can it use exchange rate devaluation to stimulate its 
export sector as a means of offseting the negative 
impact of massive budget consolidation on domestic 
demand. 

In the context of an ECB that aims for price stability in 
the eurozone, the only realistic way that Greece can 
regain international competitiveness without currency 
devaluation is by engineering a 20-30 per cent fall in 
domestic wages and prices over time. This would necessarily 
involve many years of painfully slow economic 
growth and very high unemployment. It would also 
contribute to raising Greece’s public debt to a GDP 
ratio beyond 150 per cent, or to a level that Greece 
could hardly support without a major debt restructuring. 


An even surer recipe for many years of a depressed 
economy and extraordinarily high unemployment levels 
would be an attempt by the Greek government to 
reduce its budget deficit over the next three years by 
the 10 percentage points of GDP needed to bring that 
defi cit into line with the Maastricht criteria. Even if one 
were to assume that the Keynesian multiplier was only 

1.2 for Greece, a 10 percentage point of GDP cut in 
public spending must be expected to directly cause 
Greece’s GDP to contract by 12 per cent over that period. 
Since tax collections in Greece are around 40 per cent 
of its GDP, were GDP indeed to decline by 12 per cent, 
Greece would lose around 5 percentage points of 
GDP in tax collections. The net upshot would be that 
Greece’s budget balance would only have improved 
by 5 percentage points of GDP rather than the desired 
10 percentage points of GDP. This would necessitate 
yet a further round of savage public expenditure cuts 
that would only further depress the Greek economy. 

Taking this line of reasoning to its logical conclusion, 
it would seem that if Greece is indeed to keep cutting 
budget spending to meet the Maastricht criteria, while 
at the same time getting no benefit from a depreciated 
exchange rate, Greece could very well see its GDP declining 
over the next few years by a cumulative 15 to 
20 per cent. In that context, Greek policymakers might 
want to take a close look at the experience of the hap


less Latvia, which is some eighteen months ahead of 
Greece in the application of a hair-shirt fiscal austerity 
programme under IMF supervision to preserve its 
euro currency peg. Latvia’s GDP has already fallen by 
18 per cent and the IMF is expecting a further 4 per 
cent decline in 2010. Equally disturbing is the fact that 
for all of its economic pain, Latvia’s budget deficit remains 
around 8 per cent of GDP, more than double the 
desired Maastricht target. 

It is difficult to believe that Greece’s social and political 
fabric would hold together were Greece’s recession 
to be half as deep as that being experienced in 
Latvia. It is also difficult to believe that a major Greek 
recession would not result in a wave of household defaults 
that would shake the Greek banking system to 
its very roots and that would spark the very capital 
fl ight that Greece is seeking to avoid. 

Greece Is Not Alone 

Within this sombre picture, there is one silver lining 
for the Greek government. It is the knowledge that 
the European Central Bank and the European Commission 
are as fearful of the consequences of a Greek 
default on the US$ 400 billion in its sovereign debt as 
the Greek government itself is. Not only would a Greek 
sovereign default deal a major blow to a still very fragile 
European banking system, it would also focus the 
market’s full fury on the other highly vulnerable eurozone 
members. Spain, Ireland and Portugal all have 
very troubling public finances and international competitiveness 
problems that must be expected to raise 
serious questions in the markets as to whether they 
would be the next dominoes to fall. 

At five times the size of the Greek economy and with 
around US$ 1 trillion in sovereign debt, the Spanish 
economic domino is Greece’s most potent argument 
for a European bailout. In all too many ways, the Spanish 
economy suffers from the same sort of economic 
vulnerabilities as the Greek economy does. Worse 
still, in some ways the Spanish economy is less well 
placed than that of Greece to endure many years of 
defl ationary budget policy. 

Over the past decade, mainly as a result of a housing 
market boom that dwarfed the one in the USA, the 
Spanish economy has lost even more price and wage 
competitiveness than the Greek economy. This loss in 
international competitiveness has been an important 
factor underlying the widening of Spain’s external current 
account deficit to a peak of US$ 150 billion, or 
more than 10 per cent of GDP, in 2007. It has also con-

Intereconomics 2010 | 2 

94 

Forum Forum 
tributed to the exponential increase in Spain’s gross 
external debt burden to a staggering 135 per cent of 
GDP at present. 

Now that the Spanish housing bubble has started to 
burst, it has become all too evident how overly dependent 
Spain’s public finances were on property 
market related revenue collections. From a modest 
surplus in 2007, Spain’s budget position has swung 
dramatically to a deficit of 11 ½ per cent of GDP by 
2009, a level not materially different in relative size 
from that of Greece. 

Like Greece, Spain will be required to adhere to many 
years of budget austerity if it is to regain its more than 
30 per cent loss in international competitiveness and 
to restore budget sustainability within the straightjacket 
of eurozone membership. Yet Spain will have to 
start the budget consolidation process with an unemployment 
rate already close to 20 per cent. And Spain 
will have to engage in draconian budget cutting at the 
very time that the continuing bursting of its housing 
bubble will be a major drag on the Spanish economy. 
Under these circumstances, it is difficult to see how 
Spain’s banking system will be spared a major crisis 
sometime down the road. 

Kicking the Can Forward 

A Greek sovereign debt default would almost certainly 
trigger severe market pressure on Spain, Ireland and 
Portugal, which the market would perceive as being 
the next countries in line to default. By meaningfully 
raising these countries’ borrowing costs, such market 
pressure would make it virtually impossible for 
these countries to service their sovereign debt obligations. 
Armed with this knowledge, one can be sure 
that the Greek government will exert its leverage to extract 
a bailout from its main European partners since 
this is vital to staving off the European periphery’s 
day of reckoning. Despite all of the German government’s 
huffing and puffing about moral hazard risk 
and Greece’s lack of policy commitment, it knows that 
when the chips are down, the very continuation of the 
eurozone experiment in its present form is in question. 

Sadly, when Greece does get bailed out, be it by its 
European partners or by the IMF, there will be a basic 
question that will go unasked: are Greece’s long-
term economic interests best served by delaying what 
seems to be Greece’s inevitable need to restructure 
its sovereign debt and to devalue its currency? Not 
only will a bailout needlessly put the Greek economy 
through the wringer and worsen the starting point 

from which an eventual Greek economic recovery 
might begin, it will also cruelly saddle Greece with a 
mountain of official debt that Greece will not be allowed 
to reschedule. 

Europe in Denial 

Instead of considering how best an eventual breakup 
of the euro in its present form might be handled, 
European policymakers are toying with the quixotic 
idea of setting up a European Monetary Fund. They 
do so in the full knowledge that the setting up of such 
a fund will require Treaty modification. And they do so 
knowing that, if the tortuous process of ratifying the 
Lisbon Treaty is anything by which to go, gaining final 
approval for a European Monetary Fund could take at 
least fi ve years. 

It is fanciful to think that markets will patiently hold 
onto their Greek paper while the European policymakers 
take their sweet time setting up an institutional 
change as far-reaching as the EMF. It is also difficult to 
see how such a fund would do anything to reverse the 
enormous damage that has already been done to the 
Club Med countries’ economic fundamentals. It would 
seem to do little good to close the stable door now 
after the horse has long since bolted. 

The recent strong public outcry in Germany against 
the notion of bailing Greece out should give one pause 
before suggesting the establishment of a new European 
Monetary Fund that should be funded by market 
borrowing backed by member country guarantees. 
The German public will rightly ask how lending by the 
proposed European Monetary Fund to member countries 
in distress would be different from the sort of 
sovereign bailouts that are supposed to be proscribed 
by existing eurozone agreements. They will also understand 
that it would be the German taxpayer rather 
than the markets that would be left holding the bag in 
the event of any failure by Greece to repay. 

It would seem that Europe’s interests would be better 
served if its policymakers were to recognise the basic 
flaws in the eurozone concept as patently revealed 
by the outsized internal and external imbalances of its 
Club Med members. The fact that the euro’s founders 
deliberately omitted the mapping out of an exit strategy 
from the euro does not mean that the arrangement 
will not be torn asunder by the insuperable vulnerabilities 
of its peripheral member countries. Better that the 
eventual break-up of the euro in its present form occurs 
in a well thought out manner than in a disorderly 
fashion driven by market forces. 

Intereconomics 2010 | 2 

full details contact us 60 pages